Our old theory of what to do was wrong, and we don’t have a new one.
Former Lehman Brothers CEO Richard Fuld is sworn in before
testifying Sept. 1, 2010, to the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission
about the causes of the 2008 financial and banking meltdown. We don't
know much more now than we did then, or in 2008.
Photo by Chip Somodevilla/Getty Images
Photo by Chip Somodevilla/Getty Images
This weekend marks the fifth anniversary of Lehman Brothers’ final,
chaotic descent into bankruptcy. The investment bank wasn’t the first
American financial institution to drown in bad bets on mortgage-backed
securities. But unlike those that had come before, Lehman wasn’t covered
by the FDIC and its resolution process. And despite the scrambling
efforts of the Treasury Department and Federal Reserve, there was no way
to quasi-save it through the kind of shotgun marriage that was deployed
to sell Bear Stearns to JPMorgan Chase. Lehman was going down, and all
officials could do was wait to see what happened next.
What happened next, of course, was a full-scale financial panic—one
that the Fed and the Treasury spent the next year fighting under two
presidents. They wanted, desperately, to avoid the collapse of the
American banking system. And contrary to loud and fashionable lines of
criticism then and now, they overwhelmingly did it not out of corruption
or fealty to Wall Street but out of sincere belief that ending
financial panic would be critical to helping real people and the real
economy. To their credit, they succeeded at stemming the disaster much
better than their contemporaneous critics allowed.
But they don’t like to admit to a plain truth that’s obvious to most
everyone else: that ending the financial crisis and healing the banking
system turned out to be much less important than we believed at the
time.
One of the most infamous documents of the Obama era is a January 2009 projection
attributed to Jared Bernstein and Christina Romer making the case for
the president’s stimulus plan. They forecast that with the president’s
plan in place, unemployment would peak in the third quarter of 2009 at 8
percent and then fall to about 5 percent by the second quarter of 2013.
Oops.
The really striking thing about the paper isn’t what they say about
the stimulus. It’s what they say about a world of no stimulus. In this
world unemployment peaks at 9 percent in the middle of 2010. After that
it falls quite rapidly to about 5.5 percent in early 2013 and then
precisely matches the no-stimulus scenario by the end of this year.
Which is to say they believed then what policymakers at all levels
believed—that there was simply no way to have a grinding years-long
period of seemingly endless slow growth and mass unemployment. A harder
recessionary fall would mean a sharper snapback. Cushioning the blow was
sensible and humane, but the actual difference would be short-lived.
And yet experts knew that, at least in an academic sense, prolonged slumps were
possible. That’s what happened during the Great Depression of the
1930s. Ben Bernanke summed up the conventional wisdom on this point in
2002, in his
tribute speech on Milton Friedman’s 90th birthday—back
when Bernanke was a Fed governor but not yet running the show.
“Regarding the Great Depression,” Bernanke said, addressing himself
directly to Friedman, “you’re right, we did it. We’re very sorry. But
thanks to you, we won’t do it again.”
The embedded meaning here: The Depression occurred because the
Federal Reserve of the time had allowed widespread bank failures to
sharply reduce the amount of money circulating in the country. This
shortage of currency led to falling prices, which became a vicious
cycle. With prices headed downward, everyone wanted to defer business
investments and major purchases as far into the future as possible. That
only increased the excess demand for money and intensified the cycle of
deflation. The lesson was clear—at all costs, prevent a spiral of bank
failures, currency shortage, and falling prices. Get that done, and the
system will return to equilibrium.
By this standard, the powers that be have performed quite well. Leading measures of financial system stress spiked during the crisis but rapidly returned to normal. Banks have failed, but the banking system
is alive. Ordinary households and businesses have no trouble finding
someplace safe to put their money, and creditworthy borrowers can get
loans. There’s been no cycle of deflation.
Yet the self-correcting economy we were promised hasn’t materialized. The unemployment rate remains high, even as the share of the population looking for a job keeps shrinking.
And there’s no real mystery as to why the labor market has remained
sick. Despite the hype about robots and jobless recoveries, employment growth has been about as weak as you’d expect
given weak overall GDP growth. This is the deepest and most frightening
lesson of the financial crisis—the automatic bounce-back mechanism
doesn’t actually exist. The need for some extra boost—whether from
fiscal stimulus, or monetary policy aimed at deliberately increasing inflation—is deeper and more profound than the Obama administration realized at the time.
Putting the measures in place for that extra boost would be an
extremely difficult political lift. But the emergency measures that
saved the banking system in the fall and winter of 2008–2009 were a
tough lift too. They got done because policy elites regarded them as
necessary. Today, those at the helm at the time defend that judgment,
but add the qualification that what was necessary was “not sufficient.”
Yet the insufficiency of the banking rescue ought to raise the question
of whether it really was necessary. The bailouts of financial
institutions were supposed to put the country on a self-correcting
long-term path, even in the absence of other pro-growth measures. If
they don’t do that, then the billions spent on TARP are like any other
kind of fiscal stimulus spending—just a form targeted at a segment of
society that’s unusually undeserving of public assistance.
Bailout fatigue is rampant, but there’s absolutely no consensus on what we should do when faced with the next major economic downturn. Five years ago Bernanke and others at least had the excuse that they thought
they knew what to do. Today we know that bank-centered theory of
depression prevention was wrong, but haven’t embraced a new one. The
continued imperfections in America’s financial regulations are scary.
But the lack of a plan for what to do next time those flaws come to
light—that’s much scarier.
No comments:
Post a Comment